A
considerable part of my (admittedly brief) life has been invested in politics,
and I have become an individual with firm and, what I believe to be,
well-contemplated views about politics. I would describe my views as somewhat
intricate and complex (though I wouldn’t be surprised if everyone thought that
about their own political views), and so I have attempted to cover the
foundational qualities of my politics here. It is plainly obvious that the
sharing of one’s political views can muster some sordid emotions in others who
disagree. As a result, I would highly encourage readers to recognise this as an
elaboration on my political views so that my way of thinking can be better
understood, rather than something more offensive. Additionally, as I’m British
and live in the United Kingdom, it is worthy of note that my political views,
resulting, have come to reflect UK politics.
If I were
to give a general name to my political views, it would be this: liberal
socialism. It is not a new political philosophy, and it is not a relatively
unknown one, but it is one I wish to establish here as the principal pillar of
my own political philosophy.
In terms
of economic reasoning, I would describe liberal socialism as pragmatic,
particularly when considering where the boundary sits between the public sector
and the private sector. To put it simply, liberal socialism is the philosophy
of a largely pragmatically mixed economy, not a mainly ideological one, and is
comfortable with both private ownership and public ownership. This would be in
contrast with some other political ideologies that sit on the centre and centre-left
of British politics, like democratic socialism which generally favours public
ownership and social democracy which generally favours private ownership (within
reason). The aim of liberal socialism is not really to have an ideologically
defined preference, and instead, a preference that is determined by logic where
it is possible to have one. The determination of this boundary, I would say,
can be generally found via the understanding of the potential for private
competition in the relevant matter. Therefore, to conclude whether a service or
industry should be publicly owned or be left to the private sector, one should ask
the question: does this service or industry have the potential for competition? If the answer to that question is yes, then it could be considered that
the relevant service or industry should be left to the private sector,
otherwise, the public sector should perhaps take ownership.
The
advantages of competition are obvious – good competition
can improve service or industry quality, improve supply, and reduce costs. In
parts of the private sector where competition is lacking, problems can begin to
occur. In these cases, private monopolies can begin to form and grow, which
brings with it the inherent dangers of burgeoning inefficiency, poorer services,
and greater costs. Resultingly, the government must consider whether the
relevant service or industry can be made to be more competitive with
intervention, such as by breaking monopolies up into smaller parts, or whether
it would be advantageous to bring the monopolies into public ownership. Generally
speaking, state-owned monopolies tend to be more efficient than private
monopolies, as there is (if handled correctly) less opportunity for
fragmentation, better nationwide centralisation, and a closer relationship
between the service or industry and the relevant regulators. Regulators play an
important role in making sure that services or industries work in a way that is
most advantageous to those using those services or industries, and making sure those
services are as close to regulators as possible is important. Closely-knit
services and regulators are much better able to cooperate and function
optimally together, and is, therefore, better for everyone. As a result, state
ownership should be seriously considered in cases where the private sector
fails to provide a competitive alternative.
It should
be reiterated, however, that where competition is viable within the private
sector, the relevant services and industry should remain within the domain of
the private sector. Whether a monopoly is privately owned or state-owned, there
can be the encouragement of waste and greater bureaucracy, the disadvantages of
which are plain. Nevertheless, the private sector still needs to be regulated.
To suggest that the private sector can wholly regulate itself is fanciful and
not relevant to the real world. Where it is possible to do so, private
organisations and companies will cut corners and make decisions that are more
widely disadvantageous in order to improve profits and organisational
performance. As a result, the government must take steps to encourage better and
more widely advantageous behaviour within the private sector.
One way
of performing this, as has been previously mentioned, is the use of state-owned
regulators which make sure that private companies operate in line with relevant
regulations and laws. This can have the obvious benefit of forcing private
companies to perform in a much more desirable way. One should, however, remain
mindful of over-regulation. Over-regulation can occur if the regulatory burden
on parts of the private sector is so great that it prevents much of the
advantages of competition from being harnessed. In these cases, the government
must decide whether deregulation is possible. If deregulation is possible, then
the government should undertake such steps to encourage greater competition. If
deregulation is not possible (such as if extensive regulations are necessary
for safety or other similar matters), then the government should consider
nationalisation. Over-regulated organisations within the private sector are
effectively run by the government, so it would make practical sense to simply
have those organisations be owned by the government. Remember, however, not to
be confused between over-regulated and extensively regulated. Some parts of the
economy need to be regulated extensively but are not necessarily over-regulated
and can still operate competitively, such as in the case of the banking sector.
One can
also argue for the case of having state-owned companies operating within competitive
areas of the economy in order to provide some state-encouraged competition.
This can be useful in cases where a part of the economy has the potential to be
competitive but isn’t due to various private organisations synchronising with
each other to maintain growth and profits without directly challenging one
another. On this basis, I would say it is wholly legitimate to have state-owned
organisations operate within a competitive market.
With regard
to taxation, it should be argued that tax for individuals should be kept
relatively low if possible, but only if it is economically prudent to do so. Regardless,
however, the tax burden should be extremely low for those on lower incomes and
should be substantially higher for those on vastly high incomes. Redistribution
is a core tenet of liberal socialism as it is important that wealth can be
distributed throughout society in such a way as to make sure each person has a
fair chance at life. In terms of the taxation of corporations, levels of tax
should, ideally, remain broadly in line with other developed nations.
Over-taxation may cause our economy to be less attractive to foreign
investment, and under-taxation may restrict the state from receiving vital financial
support for the services it provides. I would say, however, that the government
should subsidise the self-employed and small businesses more than they
currently are, in such a way as to effectively give them a tax cut. The ability
of small businesses to succeed is especially difficult even in the best of
economic times, and the provision of better state support could allow them more
breathing room to find their profitable niche and become more competitive in
the long term.
On a
social level, societal improvement is core. Unlike the words attributed to
Margaret Thatcher, there is such a thing as a society, and for our country to
become a generally better place, our society must be nourished. One of the
great crises that has emerged from Thatcherite Britain is the overriding feeling
of toxic individualism that has corrupted society. A view instilled during the
1980s is that an individual should be concerned for themselves, their families,
and no one else. This is the foundation of Thatcherism and is the antithesis of
the social attitude espoused by liberal socialism. The affairs of each
individual outside our four walls should matter to us. When we create a society
which sees individuals more willing to respect and support others within their communities,
we will observe societal growth that brings all of us closer together. Making
such progress could mean we see a reduction in bigotry, violence, crime, and
anti-social behaviour. Furthermore, a more inclusive and warm society is one
which will impact our children too. The quality of a child’s education will
determine a great deal in how the child continues to develop as a human being. Children
who are brought up in deprivation today are more likely to struggle at school,
and a good first step would be to build a society in which the effects of
deprivation and poverty on families can be relieved. Thus, not only do we need adequate
support from the government to improve the conditions in which millions of
people live in our country, but we need a doctrine from the government which espouses
the need for human beings to work together to reach something greater.
On a
final point, and drawing on what has already been mentioned, liberal socialism
champions freedom. To possess true freedom, I believe, amongst other things,
you need two vital qualities: to be educated and to have rights. To have human
rights means you are afforded the tangible means to be free, and to be educated
means you are provided with the knowledge to think freely. As a result, an
individual’s human rights and access to good quality education are core. As
previously mentioned, to receive a good education, children must be allowed the
opportunity to grow up in a society that allows them to be educated, regardless
of background or circumstances. Furthermore, I would add that it must become a fundamental
principle of liberal socialism that provisions for lifetime education are
employed so that any individual at any point in their life has the ability to
access educational services. Additionally, human rights are imperative in the
view of liberal socialism. They are non-negotiable and must be maintained completely
without compromise. This may sound absolutist and extreme to some, but the reasoning
is simple: human rights must be accepted in full, or it is not accepted at all.
If any part of our human rights is curtailed, then all of it is at risk of
being dissolved, and that is not something that is at all in keeping with the
liberal socialist philosophy. To be a liberal socialist, in my view, you must always
champion human rights in all places and for all people.
I could continue writing about my views for an eternity, but I think I have managed to articulate generally what my views are and what liberal socialism is from my perspective. So, finally,
I just wish to add that I hope that you’ve found my views on liberal socialism
and why I’m a liberal socialist interesting. Perhaps it’s given you an opportunity
for thought about whether you agree or disagree with my view?